A. Advani, E. Ash, A. Boltachka, D. Cai, and I. Rasul (2024)
Issues of racial justice and economic inequalities across racial and ethnic groups have risen
to the top of public debate. Economists ability to contribute to these debates is based on the
body of race-related research. We study the volume and content of race-related research in
economics and examine the implicit incentives to produce such work. We do so for a corpus
of 225,000 economics publications from 1960 to 2020 to which we apply an algorithmic
approach to classify race-related work, and construct paths to publication for 22,000 NBER
and 10,000 CEPR working papers posted over the last few decades. We present three new
facts. First, since 1960 less than 2% of economics publications have been race-related, with
such work being balkanized into a few fields and largely absent from many others. There is an
uptick in such work in the mid 1990s. Among the top-5 journals this is driven by the AER,
QJE and the JPE. Econometrica and the REStud have each cumulatively published fewer
than 15 race-related articles since 1960. Second, on content, while over 50% of race-related
publications in the 1970s focused on Black individuals, by the 2010s this had fallen to 20%.
There has been a steady decline in the share of race-related research on discrimination since
the 1980s, with a rise in the share of studies on identity. Finally, irrespective of field, race-
related working papers do not have worse publication outcomes compared to non race-related
working papers, in terms of publication likelihood, quality of publication, publication lags
and citations. Hence conditional on working papers being produced, the publications process
provides little disincentive to work on race-related issues. We discuss policy implications
stemming from our findings on economists’ ability to contribute to debates on race and
ethnicity in the economy.
Using administrative data on the globally connected super-rich in the UK, we study the effect of a large tax reform on migration behaviour. Prior to 2017, offshore investment returns for `non-doms' – individuals tax-resident in the UK but with connections to other countries – were untaxed. People making use of that tax status are strongly concentrated at the top of the income distribution: 86% are in the UK top 1% and 29% in the top 0.1% once overseas investment income is taken into account. A reform in 2017 brought long-stayers, who had been in the UK for at least 15 of the last 20 years, into the standard tax system, reducing their effective net-of-average-tax rate by 18%. We find that emigration responses were modest: our central estimate is that the emigration rate increases by 0.26 percentage points for a 1% decline in the net-of-tax rate, and we can rule out increases larger than 0.4 percentage points. Dispelling fears that the targeted taxpayers were able to circumvent the tax hike, we find large average increases in income reported and tax paid in the UK of more than 150%.
Should Capital Gains be tax privileged?
A. Advani, H. Hughson, A. Lonsdale, and A. Summers (2024)
Using administrative data on the universe of UK taxpayers, we leverage major
top tax rate reforms in the UK and France to evaluate how much top earners
respond to tax increases by migrating. We document four main facts. First,
looking across foreigners we find a migration semi-elasticity with respect to the
net-of-average-tax rate of -0.2, somewhat lower than has been found for specific
groups studied previously. Second, migration responses are driven by those with
the highest predicted baseline emigration probability, highlighting the importance
of accounting for heterogeneity. Third, there is little migration response from
natives. Finally, we estimate the long term impact of tax changes on the stock
of migrants among UK top earners taking a structural approach, and find that
even our modest migration elasticity implies substantial stock changes in the
long run.
In this paper we show the importance of international ties amongst the UK’s global economic elite, by exploiting administrative data derived from tax records. We show how this data can be used to shed light on the kind of transnational dynamics which have long been hypothesised to be of major significance in the UK, but which have previously proved intractable to systematic study. Our work reveals the enduring and distinctive influence of long-term imperial forces, especially to the former ‘white settler’ ex-dominions which have been called the ‘anglosphere’. These are allied to more recent currents associated with European integration and the rise of Asian economic power. Here there are especially strong ties to the ‘old EU-6’ nations of France, Germany, Netherlands, Belgium, Luxembourg, and Italy. The incredible detail and universal coverage of our data means that we can study those at the very top with a level of granularity that would be impossible using traditional survey sources. We find compelling support for the public perception that non-doms are disproportionately highly affluent individuals who can be viewed as a part of a global elite. However, whilst there is some evidence for the stereotype of the global wealthy parking themselves in the UK, this underplays the significance of the working rich. Our analysis also reveals the remarkable concentration of non-doms in central areas of London.
Aggregate taxable capital gains in UK have tripled in past
decade. Using confidential administrative data on the universe
of UK taxpayers, we show that including gains changes the
picture of UK inequality over the past two decades. These
taxable gains are largely repackaged income, so their exclusion
biases the picture of inequality. Including them changes who is
at the top of the distribution, adding more business owners and
older people. The share of income plus gains (both pre- and
post-tax) going to the top 1% is 3pp higher than for
income only, and this gap has been steadily rising.
Poor households regularly borrow and lend to smooth consumption,
yet we see much less borrowing for investment. This cannot be
explained by a lack of investment opportunities, nor by a lack
of resources available for investment. This paper provides a
novel explanation for this puzzle: informal risk sharing can
crowd out investment. I extend the canonical model of limited
commitment in risk-sharing networks to allow for lumpy
investment. The key insight is that the cost of losing insurance
is lower for a household that has invested, since it has an
additional stream of income. This limits its ability to credibly
promise future transfers, and so limits its ability to borrow
from other households. The key prediction of the model is a
non-linear relationship between total income and investment at
the network level – namely there is a network level poverty
trap. I test this prediction using a randomised control trial in
Bangladesh, that provided capital transfers to the poorest
households. The data covers 27,000 households from 1,400
villages, and contain information on risk-sharing networks,
income and investment. I exploit variation in the number of
program recipients in a network to identify the threshold level
of capital provision needed at the network level for the program
to move the network out of a poverty trap and generate further
investment. I also verify additional predictions of the model
and rule out alternative explanations. My results highlight how
capital transfer programs can be made more cost-effective by
targeting communities at the threshold of the aggregate poverty
trap.
A. Advani and B. Reich (2015), IFS Working Paper W15/30
Relatively little is known about what determines whether a
heterogenous population ends up in a cooperative or divisive
situation. This paper proposes a theoretical model to understand
what social structures arise in heterogeneous populations.
Individuals face a trade-off between cultural and economic
incentives: an individual prefers to maintain his cultural
practices, but doing so can inhibit interaction and economic
exchange with those who adopt different practices. We find that
a small minority group will adopt majority cultural practices
and integrate. In contrast, minority groups above a certain
critical mass, may retain diverse practices and may also
segregate from the majority. The size of this critical mass
depends on the cultural distance between groups, the importance
of culture in day to day life, and the costs of forming a social
tie. We test these predictions using data on migrants to the
United States in the era of mass migration, and find support for
the existence of a critical mass of migrants above which social
structure in heterogeneous populations changes discretely
towards cultural distinction and segregation.
Using administrative data on the universe of UK taxpayers, we
study the contribution of migrants to the rise in UK top incomes.
We show migrants are over-represented at the top of the income
distribution, with migrants twice as prevalent in the top 0.01%
as anywhere in the bottom 97%. These high incomes are
predominantly from labour, rather than capital, and migrants are
concentrated in only a handful of industries, predominantly finance.
Almost all (90%) of the observed growth in the UK top 1%
income share over the past 20 years has accrued to migrants.
A. Advani, H. Hughson and A. Summers (2023), Oxford Review of Economic Policy (invited)
Using anonymized administrative data on the population of UK taxpayers, we show that—in line with high-profile anecdotes about the tax affairs of the rich—effective average tax rates (EATRs) decline at the top of the distribution of income and capital gains. We also document substantial variation in EATRs within remuneration level: a quarter of those in the top 1 per cent pay headline rates, while another quarter pay at least 9pp less than the headline rate. Most of this effect is driven by the composition of remuneration, with investment income having lower tax rates and capital gains having lower rates still. If all individuals with income above £100,000 paid the headline rates, this would raise tax revenue on income and gains by £23 billion on a static basis, an increase of 27 per cent in the tax paid by this group.
A. Advani and A. Summers (2022), IFS Deaton Review of Inequalities
Data
for the charts. Older versions at CAGE and IFS.
We discuss the measurement of top incomes and wealth in the UK, and options for reforming their taxation. First, we highlight the importance of capital gains and migration in understanding long-term trends in top income shares, and of survey under-coverage at the top in understanding top wealth shares. We next consider the scope for reforms to the taxation of capital to tackle these inequalities, whilst also improving the efficiency of taxation, emphasising the roles of Capital Gains Tax, Inheritance Tax and Wealth Taxes. Finally, we examine the question of who is taxed, including the tax treatment of highly mobile individuals and of trusts.
We study the effects of audits on long run compliance behaviour,
using a random audit program covering more than 53,000 tax
returns. We find that audits raise reported tax liabilities for
five years after audit, effects are longer lasting for more
stable sources of income, and only individuals found to have
made errors respond to audit. 60-65% of revenue from
audit comes from the change in reporting behaviour. Extending
the standard model of rational tax evasion, we show these
results are best explained by information revealed by audits
constraining future misreporting. Together these imply that more
resources should be devoted to audits, audit targeting should
account for reporting responses, and audit threat letters miss a
key benefit of audit
We compare two approaches to measuring UK top income shares—the
share of income going to particular subgroups, such as the top
1%. We set out four criteria that an ideal top share series
should satisfy: (i) comparability between numerator and
denominator; (ii) comparability over time; (iii) international
comparability; and (iv) practical sustainability. Our preferred
approach meets three of these; by contrast the approach
currently used to produce UK fiscal income series meets none of
them. Changing to our preferred approach matters quantitatively:
the share of income going to the top 1% is 2 percentage points
higher, but rising more slowly, than under the alternative.
How does economics compare to other social sciences in its study
of issues related to race and ethnicity? We assess this using a
corpus of 500,000 academic publications in economics, political
science, and sociology. Using an algorithmic approach to
classify race-related publications, we document that economics
lags far behind the other disciplines in the volume and share of
race-related research, despite having higher absolute volumes of
research output. Since 1960, there have been 13,000 race-related
publications in sociology, 4,000 in political science, and 3,000
in economics. Since around 1970, the share of economics
publications that are race-related has hovered just below 2%
(although the share is higher in top-5 journals); in political
science the share has been around 4% since the mid-1990s, while
in sociology it has been above 6% since the 1960s and risen to
over 12% in the last decade. Finally, using survey data
collected from the Social Science Prediction Platform, we find
economists tend to overestimate the amount of race-related
research in all disciplines, but especially so in economics.
A. Advani, T. Ooms, and A. Summers (2022), Journal of Social Policy
Policymakers tend to ‘treasure what is measured’ and overlook
phenomena that are not. In an era of increased reliance on
administrative data, existing policies also often determine what
is measured in the first place. We analyse this two-way
interaction between measurement and policy in the context of the
investment incomes and capital gains that are missing from the
UK’s official income statistics. We show that these ‘missing
incomes’ change the picture of economic inequality over the past
decade, revealing rising top income shares during the period of
austerity. The underestimation of these forms of income in
official statistics has diverted attention from tax policies
that disproportionately benefit the wealthiest. We urge a
renewed focus on how policy affects and is affected by
measurement.
We use administrative tax data from audits of self-assessment
tax returns to understand what types individuals are most likely
to be non-compliant. Non-compliance is common, with one-third of
taxpayers underpaying by some amount, although half of aggregate
under-reporting is done by just 2% of taxpayers. Third
party reporting reduces non-compliance, while working in a
cash-prevalent industry increases it. However, compliance also
varies significantly with individual characteristics:
non-compliance is higher for men and younger people. These
results matter for measuring inequality, for understanding
taxpayer behaviour, and for targeting audit resources.
Capital gains are particularly complex to tax given their
infrequency, the different ways in which they are generated, and
worries about harming productivity. There are theoretical
arguments in support of everything from zero rates to high rates
of tax on capital. In this paper, I first discuss the impact of
capital gains on inequality, which often motivates discussions
about how gains should be taxed. I then set out the principles
that determine how gains should be taxed, in particular how the
tax rate should relate to income tax rates. I propose that
capital gains tax rates be equalized with income tax rates,
subject to provisions to allow gains to be ‘smoothed’ over time
and to remove inflation from the tax base. I highlight key
transitional issues in moving to such a tax structure. Finally,
I discuss the specific lessons for Canada.
This paper introduces a special issue on a Wealth Tax, which
draws together the latest thinking on wealth taxes with the aim
of filling this gap. It draws heavily on international
experience and evidence, applying these insights to the UK
context. The papers build on work undertaken for the Wealth Tax
Commission, which delivered its final report in December 2020.
The contributors to this special issue include tax practitioners
and academic lawyers as well as economists, reflecting our view
that this range of expertise is essential to evaluating the
practice, as well as principles, of a wealth tax. In this paper
we touch upon some common themes arising across the papers. We
also highlight some important remaining gaps in the evidence
base on wealth taxes, particularly on the measurement of wealth
and behavioural responses at the very top of the wealth
distribution.
In this paper we model the revenue that could be raised from an
annual and a one-off wealth tax of the design recommended by
Advani, Chamberlain and Summers (2020). We examine the distributional effects of the tax, both in
terms of wealth and other characteristics. We also estimate the
share of taxpayers who would face liquidity constraints in
meeting their tax liability. We find that an annual wealth tax
charging 0.18% on wealth above £500,000 could generate
£10 billion in revenue, before admin costs. Alternatively, a
one-off tax charging 4.8% (effectively 0.96% per
year, paid over a 5-year period) on wealth above the same
threshold, would generate £250 billion in revenue. To put our
revenue estimates into context, we present revenue estimates and
costings for some commonly-proposed reforms to the existing set
of taxes on capital.
In this paper, we review the existing empirical evidence on how
individuals respond to the incentives created by a net wealth
tax. Variation in the overall magnitude of behavioural responses
is substantial: estimates of the elasticity of taxable wealth
vary by a factor of 800. We explore three key reasons for this
variation: tax design, context, and methodology. We then discuss
what is known about the importance of individual margins of
response and how these interact with policy choices. Finally, we
use our analysis to systematically narrow down and reconcile the
range of elasticity estimates. We argue that a well-designed
wealth tax would reduce the tax base (of reported wealth) by
7-17% if levied at a tax rate of 1%.
Household wealth is profoundly important for living standards.
We show that wealth inequality in the UK is high and has
increased slightly over the past decade as financial asset
prices increased in the wake of the financial crisis. But data
deficiencies are a major barrier in understanding the true
distribution, composition and size of household wealth. We find
that the most comprehensive survey of household wealth in the UK
does a good job of capturing the vast majority of the wealth
distribution, but that nearly £800 billion of wealth held
by the very wealthiest UK households is missing. We also find
tentative evidence to suggest that survey measures of
high-wealth families undervalue their assets – our central
estimate of the true value of wealth held by households in the
UK is 5% higher than the survey data suggests.
A. Advani, T. Kitagawa and T. Słoczyński (2019),
Journal of Applied Econometrics
We consider two recent suggestions for how to perform an
empirically motivated Monte Carlo study to help select a
treatment effect estimator under unconfoundedness. We show
theoretically that neither is likely to be informative except
under restrictive conditions that are unlikely to be satisfied
in many contexts. To test empirical relevance, we also apply the
approaches to a real-world setting where estimator performance
is known. Both approaches are worse than random at selecting
estimators which minimise absolute bias. They are better when
selecting estimators that minimise mean squared error. However,
using a simple bootstrap is at least as good and often better.
For now researchers would be best advised to use a range of
estimators and compare estimates for robustness.
A. Advani and B. Malde (2018),
Journal of Economic Surveys
Understanding whether and how connections between agents
(networks) such as declared friendships in classrooms,
transactions between firms, and extended family connections,
influence their socio-economic outcomes has been a growing area
of research within economics. Early methods developed to
identify these social effects assumed that networks had
formed exogenously, and were perfectly observed, both of which
are unlikely to hold in practice. A more recent literature, both
within economics and in other disciplines, develops methods that
relax these assumptions. This paper reviews that literature. It
starts by providing a general econometric framework for linear
models of social effects, and illustrates how network
endogeneity and missing data on the network complicate
identification of social effects. Thereafter, it discusses
methods for overcoming the problems caused by endogenous
formation of networks. Finally, it outlines the stark
consequences of missing data on measures of the network, and
regression parameters, before describing potential solutions.
Current UK energy use policies, which primarily aim to reduce
carbon emissions, provide abatement incentives which vary by
user and fuel, creating inefficiency. Distributional concerns
are often given as a justification for the lower carbon price
faced by households, but there is little rationale for carbon
prices associated with the use of gas to be lower than those for
electricity. We consider reforms that raise carbon prices faced
by households, and reduce the variation in carbon prices across
gas and electricity use, improving the efficiency of emissions
reduction. We show that the revenue raised from this can be
recycled in a way that ameliorates some of the distributional
concerns. Whilst such recycling is not able to protect all
poorer households, existing policy also makes distributional
trade-offs, but does this in an opaque and inefficient way.
A. Advani and B. Malde (2018),
Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics (solicited)
In many contexts we may be interested in understanding whether
direct connections between agents, such as declared friendships
in a classroom or family links in a rural village, affect their
outcomes. In this paper we review the literature studying
econometric methods for the analysis of linear models of social
effects, a class that includes the `linear-in-means' local
average model, the local aggregate model, and models where
network statistics affect outcomes. We provide an overview of
the underlying theoretical models, before discussing conditions
for identification using observational and
experimental/quasi-experimental data.
In many contexts we may be interested in understanding whether
direct connections between agents, such as declared friendships
in a classroom or family links in a rural village, affect their
outcomes. In this paper we review the literature studying
econometric methods for the analyis of social networks. We begin
by providing a common framework for models of social effects, a
class that includes the ‘linear-in-means’ local average model,
the local aggregate model, and models where network statistics
affect outcomes. We discuss identification of these models using
both observational and experimental/quasi-experimental data. We
then discuss models of network formation, drawing on a range of
literatures to cover purely predictive models, reduced form
models, and structural models, including those with a strategic
element. Finally we discuss how one might collect data on
networks, and the measurement error issues caused by sampling of
networks, as well as measurement error more broadly.